Posted on June 30, 2013 | 4 Comments
Just when I thought my academic career was over, my first peer-reviewed academic article in five years comes out in the Journal of Consumer Culture, and I get to be a Visiting Researcher at the University of Surrey. The article in JCC is about the veg box scheme I jointly ran for 5 years, and the lessons it holds for green political thought (act local think global, as they say). It’s been published online but not yet in print, so I’ll blog some more about it when it exists on paper. Here I’m going to focus on some subsidiary themes of the paper – a critique of so-called ‘eco-pragmatism’ and the beginnings of an argument for a revised agrarian populism.
The topic occurred to me when a web search took me to the website of my recent golden rice adversary and self-styled ‘eco-pragmatist’, Graham Strouts. His latest post provides an interesting but muddled analysis of the thinking of Thomas Malthus and Karl Marx in the course of an attempt to show that eco/leftwing thought has been tarnished by what Strouts calls the ‘darker forces of environmentalism’, in the latter’s dalliances with eugenics, racial nationalism, right wing occultism and the like. Strouts proceeds from there to suggest that green thinking is largely an ideology of the far right.
Though I don’t agree with this rather extreme interpretation, it’s helped me to understand the ideological basis of ‘eco-pragmatism’ more clearly. My aim here is to pursue a different line of argument regarding Malthus and Marx as a basis for a revised agrarian populism rather than engaging with Strouts’ interpretation directly. But I do first feel the need to observe that you have to be careful with tracing intellectual lineages because, much like human inheritance, if you go far enough back everything turns out to be related to everything else. So while it’s true that there are some unsavoury political skeletons in the green closet, the fact is that eugenics was common coin amongst left and right in the early twentieth century, and one could just as easily argue that the ‘eco-pragmatist’ obsession with cities and technology is heir to the fascism of Italian futurism. Ironically, Strouts relies on an analysis by Brendan O’Neill of Spiked Online – formerly the journal of the Revolutionary Communist Party known as Living Marxism but now a mouthpiece of right-wing libertarianism – which says a lot about the perils of tracing intellectual history, particularly when the aim is to make any particular political tradition guilty by association with another one.
Anyway, I digress – on to Marx and Malthus. Because Marxism is usually considered a doctrine of the extreme left, it’s often mistakenly thought of as being the most radically anti-capitalist of philosophies. However, as has been shown by various scholars, there are deep continuities between Marx’s thought and capitalist ideology – partly in Marx’s enthusiasm for the necessity of capitalism in order to destroy other kinds of society as a precondition for the emergence of socialism, but more fundamentally in his theoretical apparatus (labour, class, dialectic, mode of production etc) which mirror the categories of capitalist thought. Like everyone, Marx was a person of his time. There’s a brilliance to much of his analysis that remains fresh and relevant today, but with the distance of well over a century it’s not hard to see the limitations: like many nineteenth century intellectuals, Marx had a taste for grand narratives of historical progress which he believed would culminate in the final perfection of an achieved proletarian revolution, and his thinking was deeply grounded in the Victorian concerns with work, class and alienation.
Malthus’s Essay on Population (1798) is well known for advancing the thesis that populations grow geometrically whereas their resource base can only grow arithmetically, so that resource scarcity checks population growth. Notoriously, this led him to opposing poverty relief on the grounds that it would only lead to further unsustainable pressures on resources, and to various other distasteful rightwing positions.
Every generation of social scientists seems destined to exhume the body of Malthus, kick it around a bit, and pronounce it thoroughly dead – but the fact that we’re still talking about him 200 years later suggests that they haven’t quite succeeded, and even perhaps that the enthusiasm to dance on his grave betrays an anxiety that the old dog may have had a point. So let’s try to sort through a few things.
First of all, Malthus was undoubtedly right that resource scarcity can and does check population growth in the natural world. This insight was a key influence on Darwin’s theory of natural selection, and it’s apparent in modern ecological studies of population dynamics, although these are very much more sophisticated than Malthus’s rather basic observations. Second, Malthus’s population theory is separable from his unpleasant politics. Marx called Malthus a ‘professional sycophant of the landed aristocracy’, which in many ways he was, but that doesn’t mean he was wrong to suggest that resource scarcities can pressurise human populations, a point that carries no logical implications for poverty policies. Or to put it another way there’s a need to distinguish between absolute and relative effects: resource scarcity may pressure a population and demand a response, but there are many ways the pressure and the response may be distributed across the population.
The main objection to Malthusian thinking is that it neglects the way that resource scarcity is ‘socially mediated’, or in other words transformed by human innovation – for example, agriculture faced a scarcity of nitrogenous fertiliser in the 19th century, but it no longer does because at the dawn of the 20th Messrs Haber and Bosch figured out how to synthesise it from air using fossil energy. It’s a fair point, but there are several complications. Here are five: (1) a social innovation enabling a switch from one non-renewable resource to another (eg. coal to oil) may defer a resource crisis, but it doesn’t undermine Malthus’s basic contention; (2) in contrast to Malthus’s rather crude population/resource analysis we now know that the relationships between natural resources and consumption are many, complex and little understood – as in the ugly modern concept of ‘ecosystem services’; it’s fairly clear that human resource use is affecting ecosystem services in all sorts of ways we barely understand with potentially deleterious long-term consequences for ourselves or our descendents; (3) likewise, there can be many complex knock-on effects from the social transformation of limits, one of which is the ‘rebound effect’ of increased population or resource use to take advantage of the newly abundant resource, prompting another Malthusian crisis; (4) although the social mediation of resource limits is almost always talked about in terms of technological innovation enabling new resources to be tapped or old ones to be tapped more efficiently, a society’s decision to limit its resource use or its numbers is no less a social mediation of resource use; (5) the social mediation of resources tells us nothing about the distribution of resources across society. To summarise crudely, if Malthusianism suffers from being an under-socialised theory, Marxism suffers from being an over-socialised one.
One final observation on Malthus – people often say that he’s been proved wrong because technical innovations have staved off Malthusian crises. This is incorrect, partly because there have been plenty of Malthusian crises of varying degrees of severity before and after Malthus (albeit depending somewhat on how you choose to define both ‘Malthusian’ and ‘crisis’) and partly because 200 years (ie. about 0.1% of human history) isn’t really long enough to judge – the ‘sustainable intensification’ brigade are forever telling us that we have to increase agricultural productivity by up to 100% over the coming decades, and the research is increasingly suggesting that this is pretty unlikely. Meanwhile, Ford Denison has pointed out that increases in food productivity have actually proceeded more slowly than predicted by Malthus, and per capita food availability globally has been declining since the 1980s. Maybe we can expect Malthus’s ghost to take another turn around the block soon.
There are endless implications to all of this, but to conclude I want to describe how it feeds into the radically different worldviews of ‘eco-pragmatism’ and agrarian populism.
‘Eco-pragmatism’ has always seemed to me largely just apologetics for business-as-usual capitalism with a bit of spurious greenwash thrown in. But I can see that if you interpret your Marx and your Malthus in certain ways its ideology may seem persuasive. So if you genuinely believe that history can be read as a series of stages, each one a successive improvement from a barbarous past to a perfectible future, and if you genuinely believe that all resource constraints can be melted away by human technical innovation then I can imagine that you might sign up to the following ‘eco-pragmatist’ principles:
But none of this is convincing to those of us who read the history and the politics differently. Instead, I’d propose the following elements for a green/agrarian populist vision:
Some of these points of difference between ‘eco-pragmatism’ and agrarian populism can be illuminated by empirical evidence, but many of them can’t. Fundamentally they’re matters of political philosophy, not scientific evidence, which is probably why debates between proponents of these different visions so often go round pointlessly in circles. Still, it’s worth trying to clarify the basic assumptions and points of difference, and I hope I’ve been able to do a bit of that here.
The last time I argued with an academic I was so terrified I thought I was going to have a stroke – I think it may have been social conditioning from my school days. It was a mini-conference on the influence of syndicalism on British Trade Unions where actual trade union activists were invited to attend – well, I’m not sure we were invited but we went anyway, it was a nice day out. Anyway, all the presentations talked about syndicalists but didn’t actually mention any (such as Tom Mann) but only mentioned Marxists who came after them and who would never have allowed themselves to be called such a thing.
Yes, I know… I’m getting to the point – and I hope you don’t mind long winded comments.
Marxists are not the only socialists. It is only academics that assume that if there is left wing resistance to something it should be looked at through the lens of dialectical materialism (and other such guff) to see if it stands up to scrutiny. The academics I just mentioned, though they probably should know better, were either deliberately whitewashing inconvenient truths from history or had no understanding of the subject they had been asked to talk about.
Marxists talk rubbish. There are millions of us out there worldwide risking their livelihoods, freedom and health to prevent unaccountable elites (who have no idea they are total bastards) from treading all over us and all Marxists can do is turn up to meetings and talk irrelevant rubbish.
Not all Marxists talk rubbish – I’m a big fan of George Galloway after he gave the American senate (no less!) a total bollocking.
The left is not irrelevant just because Marxism is. The left is relevant because it stands up for people regardless of logical inconsistences and hindsight. Were the luddites justified in smashing machinery? Had they won we would have not had the industrial revolution and therefore no welfare state and NHS. Knowing this can we say resistance then was backward?. In my opinion, no, it was their lives and they were suffering. If progress was inevitable perhaps the space could be won to have progress at their speed, in their time.
As for Malthusian thinking: ie, population growth is exponential and the land to grow food is finite. In Malthus’ day the state was not as developed as it is today, the state could not prevent people having as many babies as they wanted. But today it can, either by the use of strict laws (China) or womens education and higher standards of living (Denmark). If it wasn’t for immigration in this country our birth death ratio would also be around equal.
I could go on and on but I won’t.
Cheers,
Tom
Thanks Tom – don’t worry, I’m not really an academic any more and there’s very little I find to argue with in your comments. It’s always good to be reminded that Marxists aren’t the only socialists. I guess I have slightly more time for Marx (if not necessarily for ‘Marxists’) than you do, but a lot more time for those who, like you say, are fighting for justice and against unaccountable elites – including those fighting for a just and sustainable local agriculture, on which front Marxism’s record is abysmal. I could go on and on too about the need to detach the concept of ‘progress’ (in the sense of ‘improvement’) from the over-hyped, Panglossian, techno-fixing, historicist conception of it as limitless human perfectibility peddled by the ‘eco-pragmatists’, who are quite happy not only to accept but also to applaud the destruction of sustainable and viable farm livelihoods as means to their ends. But I think we’re probably in agreement over that. Somehow, though, we need to find ways of challenging the ideology of ‘progress’ without succumbing to the usual charge of romanticism, nostalgia, luddism etc. Oh, and I agree with you about the Luddites…
“it’s possible that the environmental problems we currently face can be remedied by large-scale, high-tech solutions, but there are plenty of grounds for suspecting otherwise: perhaps the accumulating evidence for the failure of such approaches suggests the model itself may be flawed”
But then isn’t there there here the problem with populism? The large scale hi-tech has been popular in large part for the narrative simplicity involved. While decentralised small-scale systems may be part of the solution and they may be intrinsically more complex, and even nuanced, still they can hold they same danger and temptation to prefer narrative simplicity. I am a huge fan of organic farming – but is it seriously ever going to break out of it’s 1% of UK food production ghetto?
“past societies should not be revered as more authentic or holistic than our own, but nor should they be scorned as less ‘developed’”
An excellent point. Traditions and traditional are so often in the eye of the beholder, as lifestyles were driven by social and economic contexts. While contrariwise, recognising that we have a freedom and choices in the reinvention and creation of traditions, tends to be submerged by double-think that demands authenticity from denying the importance reinvention and creation have always had in thriving traditions.
“the ‘hardness’ of peasant life stems mostly from its vulnerability to exploitation by landlords and usurers, and the solution lies in pro-peasant political reform, not expropriation of peasant holdings.”
I was struck by your summary of Strouts view, that it would be pro-enclosures, anti-commoning. But how do those peasants get to the table where they can defend themselves, without economic clout? It is easy to wish agrarian reform had gone otherwise, and I think especially in the cases of wetlands and highlands a poor trade was made. Yet, the movement to defend the commons gave rise from defence of peasant resources, to a deeply middle class reinvention, the National Trust. Very worthy of critique (Monbiot’s Think Like A Forest doing so resoundingly), yet, able to defend land use patterns and landscapes much more effectively than any pro-peasant political reforms alone..
” ‘back to nature woo-woo naturalistic beliefs’ can be, I admit, a bit of a problem but so too can hyper-rationalism”
And something Strouts employs, which is to say if it doesn’t happen in a lab or there is no published paper, then no case can be made. There are modes of debate where that has to be the case, but there are also reasonable hypotheses, fieldwork, and non-quantitative but meaningful ways of stacking up arguments against one another.
“‘eco-pragmatism’ itself as a ‘death cult’: fearful of death”
And fearful of the inner work involved in a transformation, wedded to the idea of not facing reflection and reevaluation, through patching and running the same machine/s faster. Which risks transformation of a lot of embodied resources into scrap, that could have been remade into something better suited for purpose.
I would add to your list that agrarian populism can involve ‘downshifting’ without it being intrinsically uneconomic or elitist – we can and must make decisions about how our society engages with land and food for wider reasons than money alone.
The sweeping explanatory narratives of Malthus and Marx are like monocultures, providing interpretation everywhere in the same form. We need a polyculture, yet as you are saying one capable of being populist. Permaculture has to walk a path away both from yoghurt weaving and of becoming a science in its own right, embracing both spiritual and quantitative aspects of how to be, allowing not so much complexity that we give up trying to make sense, but not so simple that it’s too easy to explain.
Thanks for that excellent set of points. Some brief responses:
– yes, I think you’re right that there’s also a danger of narrative simplicity with decentralised systems. That’s certainly a problem with both the permaculture and organic movements. I suppose all that one can do is try to improve the narrative – not easy! And the politics are messy. Agrarian populism for me is about emphasising the importance of land-based communities, and creating a political space in which they can try to sort out their own narratives of development, rather than annihilating them through top down policies based on crashingly simplistic ideologies such as the ‘backwardness’ of peasants. That’s hard enough to do when you actually have extant agricultural communities; it seems almost impossible in places like the UK where land-based communities have almost ceased to exist. My only ideas here are pretty much to do what I’m already doing: to try to help preserve and support what still exists globally (I’m really excited to be involved in the Land Workers’ Alliance and Via Campesina on that front) and work here in the UK to reconstitute a sustainable agriculture from the grassroots. But I’m interested in further thoughts on this.
– will organics break out of its ghetto? Well, possibly – it’s doing a lot better in Europe than in the UK, partly I think because of more nuanced narratives there around the role of local farming. But I agree it’s a tall order, and it’s hard to see major global change without either significant resource pressure or a changing political narrative about how to approach sustainability
– excellent points about commons, the National Trust etc. The issue of commons is complex; I touched on it at https://chrissmaje.com/?p=139 and I’ll have to come back to it. The devil is in the detail of moving from the overall collective political agreement about land use to how that’s made to work at the local and individual level. In the UK, the urban common property regimes of municipal socialism (allotments, co-operatives, welfare institutions etc) have been much more successful than rural radicalism, with the end result of the reclaiming of rural space as a kind of heritage commons mostly for the urban middle classes which, as you say, is problematic but also indicative of political possibilities. That’s not necessarily the case for other countries, however, so again all I can do for now is wave my banner of grassroots rural reinvigoration and global political alliance-making through Via Campesina and the like in terms of reconstituting the political space. But it’s an absolutely critical issue which demands more careful thought than I’ve given it here, so thanks for raising it. It’s something I’ll try to think about and return to in the future.